Decision Making as Output and Bounded Rationality

  The classical economics theories proceed on the assumption of rational agents. Rationality implies the economic agents undertake actions or exercise choices based on the cost-benefit analysis they undertake. The assumption further posits that there exists no information asymmetry and thus the agent is aware of all the costs and benefits associated with the choice he or she has exercised. The behavioral school contested the decision stating the decisions in practice are often irrational. Implied there is a continuous departure from rationality. Rationality in the views of the behavioral school is more an exception to the norm rather a rule. The past posts have discussed the limitations of this view by the behavioral school. Economics has often posited rationality in the context in which the choices are exercised rather than theoretical abstract view of rational action. Rational action in theory seems to be grounded in zero restraint situation yet in practice, there are numerous restra

BCG, PLC and Returns to Scale

 

Management practitioners have their own jargons. Without doubt these terminologies developed help conceptualize ideas and their implementation in practice. While the observations lead to the formation of theory, it is equally true that the theoretical formulations thus developed play an input in strategy and tactics of a firm. Many management jargons and concepts owe their origin to concepts or models elucidated in economics. It would be prudent to discuss these concepts often used in management to their roots in economics. It must be stated that these roots might have often emerged subconsciously without a reference to the economic underpinnings. The current post will deal with a couple of such concepts.

 

One of the critical understandings that practitioners seek to pursue in product development is the product life cycle. It conceptualizes the journey of the product from its inception to its end cycle or the decline or perhaps death. It does give insights to the practitioners on reinvigorating the product at the appropriate times to stretch its shelf life. It does given pointers on the need to cannibalize the products as they make way for their successor generations to take over. Yet the product life cycle or PLC as it popularly called perhaps traces its origins to the understanding of the economics. To decode PLC through the prism of economics, one takes refuge in the concept of returns to scale.

 

PLC is conceptualised in four stages. Its advocates believe the product finds itself first in the introduction stage. Once it is introduced and finds itself placed in the market, it experiences a growth stage following which it attains certain maturity. Implied is the growth cannot be sustained for long periods at high levels. It slowly comes to certain sustained levels of growth. This is followed by the decline perhaps driven by demand side diminishing marginal utility or the supply side law of diminishing returns.

 

The idea of returns to scale on the other hand is driven the responsiveness of output to changes in input. In some ways, it is analogous to the concept of elasticity of output. A percentage change in inputs across board will lead to a percentage change in output. This is what the returns to scale seeks to illustrate. If the output increases more than proportional to the changes in input, then one describes the case as increasing returns to scale. If the output increases in the same proportion as the increase in inputs it is described as the concept of constant returns to scale. If the output increases less than proportional to the increase in inputs, it is described as decreasing returns to scale. In production economics literature, it is recognized that increase in an input without changes in other inputs will take us to a point wherein any further addition of input will cause the output to decline. In other words, it is the case of marginal product turning negative what one terms as a case of diminishing returns. To avoid diminishing returns, it is suggested to increase inputs across board, yet one finds diminishing returns playing its part in this context too.

 

In the product life cycle, the product when it gets introduced, it experiences an increasing returns. In the growth stage too, the increasing returns are in full play. It is not surprising. The market is barely touched while the margins are low and bound to expand. With small increases in inputs, the changes in output with respect to the market share growth as also its contribution in terms of margin will naturally increase more than proportional. Therefore the increasing returns are witnessed. Yet the market share growth has its limits. While there is a significant growth in the initial days, it is bound to reach certain limits wherein it moves from zone of elasticity to a zone of inelasticity while navigating the terrain of constant growth in between. The experience of constant returns to scale is what is observed during the maturity stage. The product has captured significant market share while contributing equally significant margins to the firm, yet the growth rate in both market share and margins is somewhat reduced. The impact of diminishing returns and the diminishing marginal utility will perhaps cause the rise of decline stage wherein the product begins to experience the cycle of decreasing returns to scale.

 

This can also be compared to the positioning adopted in Boston Consulting Group matrix, something popularly termed as BCG matrix. Formulated by Bruce Henderson, it was essentially a matrix model trying to capture the links between market growth and market share. It was the portfolio management model for strategy and marketing. It conceptualised the entire product portfolio into four different quadrants of question marks, stars, cash cows and dogs. The question marks have high growth rates but low market shares. These are the one who do demonstrate the increasing returns to scale since every addition of input would perhaps lead to more than proportional change in output (in this context the market growth rate). Yet there is no certainty that the returns to scale will on an increasing order and thus the term question marks. The stars given their high market share and high growth represent best the case of increasing returns. These give away to cash cows which while commanding high market share have low market growth. These are the products that experience the constant returns to scale. The beginning of diminishing returns is visible during the stage of dogs. Dogs are ones which have low market share and low growth rates. It is possible that the question marks might morph into dogs thus the uncertainty with respect to sustaining their increasing returns.

 

The above two examples are mere illustrations of the concept of returns to scale being used to construct different concepts in management. As the product life cycle goes, it is essentially a journey through which a product evolves while following the dictums of the returns to scale. Earlier stages, the growth will remain high since it changes more than proportional to rise in inputs whether marketing or production or any other element. Yet, the sustenance is a question mark and hence every product reaches a constant returns to scale or maturity stage. This is because market size is finite. The same logic is observed in deconstructing BCG matrix through the prism of economics. While stars no doubt yield increasing returns, cash cows experience the instance of constant returns. In fact they are classic illustration of the manifestation of economies of scale. The linkages between returns and economies are quite interesting but would be a subject matter of some other post. 

 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Decision Making as Output and Bounded Rationality

The Economics Origins of BCG Matrix

People and the Third Wave of Chinese Virus