The
post ‘Primer
on Real Life Action and Economics-I discussed how real life instances are
theorized through the conceptual prism of economics. The current post continues
the discussion applying the concept of economics to more areas.
Like in the previous post, one column
highlights the real life phenomenon what we observe, while the second column
builds up the theoretical linkage to economics.
Real Life
Practice/ phenomenon
|
Economics
Linkage
|
Live events
|
Humans enjoy live action. They love going to
stadiums to watch sports events, visit theatre to enjoy live theatre
performance, visit musical shows preferring their genre and likes. An
interesting pointer would be an analysis of these live events through the
economics angle. There is obviously the angle of utility maximization. People
prefer entertainment and leisure and these activities offer the same to the
consumers. Therefore they seek to maximise their utility by attending these
events. Yet, in understanding their clamour for maximising utility, one has
to analyse the supply physiognomies of the event. The event is one off or
strictly finite. Each sports event or contest is different and unique in
itself. Watching one cricket match is not the same as another cricket match
though they can be close substitutes. Hence the supply curve for a live
musical performance or a cricket or hockey or soccer match or athletic or for
that matter any sports contest is vertical. Irrespective of the price and
demand patterns, there is only one good on offer. The same applies to the
live theatre or live circus performances. Secondly, once you gain access to
the good, it is non rivalrous. Your enjoyment of the good is not through a
deprivation of the same for another individual. Non-rivalrous doesn’t imply
excludability. In fact it is excludable given the fact it is available only
to those who buy the tickets. Further, it is finite expansible good. It is
available only to those in the stadium or auditorium as the case might be.
Therefore it can be characterised as a club good.
|
Tax concessions to local language movies
|
Often in states like Karnataka, the movie
producers in the state language lobby with the government and pretty
successfully at for tax concessions. The logic seems simple. The lower the
price, there would be increase in quantity demanded and thus more people will
watch the movies at a lower price. Yet the answer is only partly correct.
There is more to the picture. To any movie producer, as the movie hits the
theatre, there is a threat from similar movies hitting theatres around the
same time. Moreover, as anecdotal evidence illustrates, most of the movie
collection happens in Week I. Therefore, all the irresistible need to attract
crowds during the week. The movie price is just not includes the recovery of
fixed cost of movie production (essentially sunk at that moment) but also
margins to distributors and exhibitors etc. It also comprises the tax
component. When the movie producer is unable to cut costs anywhere else and
is faced with implied demand uncertainty, he seeks to government for help.
The ostensible reason is promotion of long language movies and culture yet
the heart of it is little different. To a movie-watcher, there is a limited
budget and she has choose among multiple movies. If her consumption of movies
measured through the number of movies watch per month are measured along the
two axis, they build up the indirect utility function. The budget line
linking the willingness and ability to spend money indicates the constraint.
The tax free status for local language movie would alter the dynamics of the prices
and create swivelling of the budget along the axis. Given the constant
income, lowering of the price of one movie will shift the demand dynamics
towards a lower price movie. Alternatively we can imagine another scenario.
If all movies were tax free and the government decides to tax non local
language movies. The price of non-local language movies goes up but in the
process also has brings down the consumption of local language movie through
a process called income and substitution effect. Hence if the local language
movie price is reduced, it not only increases the demand for local language
movies but also increases the demand for non-local language movies through
the reverse operation of the income and substitution effect. Thus there is a
clamour and sub-conscious at that to seek tax exemptions for local language
movies.
|
High prices of food at airports
|
As one enters the airport and if hungry, would
naturally seek an eatery. Yet as one observes the prices, they seem
exorbitant. A small plate of Idly and Vada which perhaps costs around Rs, 40
in normal restaurant, would perhaps cost around Rs, 200 or so. There is
hardly any significant difference in the quantity nor sound great shakes in
taste. A cursory glance might indicate the cost factor at play. For a
restaurant, the costs at play are relatively limited. The rent and other
fixed costs are relatively lower. As one might expect, the rents at the
airport would obviously very high. Yet the rents are function of the vendor’s
willingness and ability to pay. Assume the prospective vendor has the ability
to pay. Yet there must be accompanied by equal willingness to pay. It is
therefore a matter of puzzle to solve on why the vendor at the airport is
willing to pay higher prices. One obvious reason is the limited space in
airport for food courts. Very few vendors would be able to put up stalls in
the food court. Moreover, given the long term nature of contracts, the first
mover advantage is significant. Therefore, the vendor has move for the kill
before others take over. Yet why there is clamour for competition in
capturing the space that is finite, rivalrous and demands high rents. The
answer again will seek towards the motivations for willingness to capture the
space. The answer lies in the ability to charge high prices. If the fixed
costs are high, they can be recovered either through volumes or economies of
scale or through high margins on individual sales. While airports do offer
small potential for scale and scope but the recovery is perhaps long over
drawn. The solution there lies in the ability to recover high margins. High
margins are possible if the good is highly inelastic and essential. In an
airport, the customer is likely to relatively insensitive to the prices.
Hence the good will be inelastic. Further relative inelasticity comes from
the location. The customer is invariably a passenger killing time before
boarding a flight or someone in hurry who want to grab a snack or two before
boarding. The supply options are limited. The number of outlets are limited.
Hence he has to do with the near monopoly situation that exists. The location
that creates fertile ground for monopoly in addition to the resolution of
need that is immediate creates the relative price inelasticity of the good.
This price inelasticity of the good under consideration makes the prices
higher at the airports.
|
Comments
Post a Comment